TAC0004

Written evidence submitted by David Brian Smith (Proprietor at Beacon Economic Forecasting)

What is the Upper Limit to Britain’s Taxable Capacity?

 

Introduction

 

The idea that there is an upper limit to a nation’s taxable capacity may go back to the dawn of settled civilisation – when predatory despots  caused unintended population collapses through mass starvation or emigration (e.g., the children of Israel leaving ancient Egypt). The concept has been long established in public finance, with the ancien regime Hapsburg and Bourbon monarchies of Spain and France notorious as a result of the economic and geopolitical decline brought about by their ‘Big Government’ conservatism. However, simply claiming that there must be an upper limit to taxable capacity is about as useful as an engineer saying that if you apply enough weight to a girder it will break.

Important practical questions normally require quantification, even if that can only be approximate. This note examines the UK historic record to roughly estimate where the upper limit of taxable capacity might be. Knowing this point is important because, after allowing for a moderate budget deficit of, say 2% to 3% of GDP and non-tax receipts of another 3%, taxable capacity defines the upper limit of sustainable government spending. This question has always been important – particularly, in wartime – but is especially so now because of the hits to the economy and public finances associated with the Covid-19 lockdown.

This note only deals with fiscal sustainability, not the appropriate size of government more generally. In previous work, I have often tried to distinguish between three main inflection points with respect to the share of government expenditure in national output (e.g., Smith (2006) or Booth (2016)).

 

Two Crucial Truisms

 

It is necessary to commence with two simple truisms that are almost entirely ignored in the political debate on ‘tax and spend’ issues. The first truism is that modern governments have effectively zero resources of their own. The corollary is that, under normal circumstances, all government spending commitments imply higher taxes, either immediately, or in the future, when the increased debt resulting from borrowing needs to be serviced.

There is a dangerous third option to higher taxes or bond-market funding, however, which is borrowing from the banking sector (defined to include the central bank). But this is only non-inflationary during the transitory period that lending to the private sector is being crowded off the asset side of bank balance sheets, a process known as financial repression. Once most bank assets are government debt, any extra loans to the public sector boost bank liabilities – i.e., their deposits – and hence broad money. This is the ‘monetisation point’ at which inflation and, in extreme cases, hyperinflation commence their take off. With the annual growth in UK M4ex broad money running at 11.3% in May and rising at an annualised 30.8% on a three-month comparison, this monetisation point may now have been passed.

The second truism, which follows on from the first, is that the tax base is not total GDP, as appears to be unquestionably believed by politicians and officials, but only the residual component of GDP after government financed spending has been subtracted. This is because it is impossible for any institution (or individual) to generate real economic resources by taxing itself. In logic, real resources invariably need to come from outside the boundaries of the bodies concerned.  This is not to deny that Local Authorities, for example, pay VAT to central government. Rather, it is that these transactions can be netted out from an economic – as distinct from an accounting - perspective.

Measurement Problems

 

A specific problem with GDP as a measure of the tax and government spending burdens is that GDP itself appears to be the proverbial piece of string. Several different measures are available in the official statistics and the measure chosen can make a difference of five or more percentage points to the alleged tax and government spending burdens (Smith (2006)). Furthermore, these competing measures can themselves be massively revised over time, as a result of major definitional changes as well as the usual bog-standard revisions. This is an important reason why it is not sensible to pass primary legislation mandating the expenditure of a fixed proportion of GDP on any given programme.

A specific problem with the officially preferred measure of GDP at market prices, as employed by the Office for Budget Responsibility (OBR), HM Treasury and the figures quoted previously, is that it is measured gross of indirect taxes and subsidies. This has several nonsensical consequences. One is that it overstates the real resources available. Another is that switching the tax burden from direct to indirect taxes (or simply raising VAT) increases reported national output, even if physical production has not changed by one iota. A conceptually superior alternative is to use the factor cost measure of GDP, which nets out indirect taxes and subsidies. This is particularly the case for longer-term historic comparisons Smith (2006)).   There is also the rather similar basic-price measure used to measure regional GDP inter alia. Table 1 shows the effect of using alternative GDP measures on the calculations for government spending and the non-oil tax burden in the most recent financial year.

Table 1: Ratios of UK General Government Expenditure and Non-Oil Taxes to Money GDP in 2019-20 Using Different GDP Measures

 

General Government Spending

Non-Oil Taxes

GDP at Market Prices

38.9%

33.3%

Gross National Income at Market Prices

39.7%

34.0%

GDP at Basic Prices

43.5%

37.2%

GDP at Factor Cost

44.1%

37.7%

Source: UK Office for National Statistics and author’s calculations.

Any measure of GDP may overstate the resources available to fund government expenditure, however, for two reasons. Firstly, the fact that the UK is an overseas debtor means that Gross National Income at Market Prices was £44.3bn less than the equivalent GDP measure in fiscal 2019-20 because of the large payments of interest, profits and dividends overseas. Second, the term ‘Gross’ in the definition of GDP means that no allowance is made for the depreciation of the capital stock. This did not matter when the capital stock was mainly long-lived assets, such as railways or steel mills. However, the Office for National Statistics (ONS) now includes software development incapital formation’, despite the notoriously short life of many such programmes (e.g., hedge fund trading software). Any categorisation of a nation as ‘living beyond its means’ should surely include a situation where public and private consumption are only sustained by increasing borrowing from overseas and running down its fixed assets? This suggests that net national income at factor cost should be the preferred measure of national income, if the ONS could compile the figures, and that the tax base is the private sector component thereof.

The Long Term Picture

 

The remainder of this note simply tries to analyse where we are now in terms of government spending and taxation using both long runs of annual data, and the most recent quarterly figures, which expire in 2020 Q1. The results suggest that, even before the Covid-19 crisis, the UK government spending to GDP ratio was high by historic standards, especially given the tight labour market and other signs that the economy was operating above capacity, such as the balance of payments deficit.  In addition, the tax burden already appeared to be close to the upper limit of historic sustainability before the current pandemic. Chart 1 (below) shows the ratio of UK general government expenditure to the historically consistent factor cost measure of GDP from 1870 to 2019. The methodology and data sources were explained in Chapters 2 and 3 of Booth (ed. 2016) and Smith (2006) and will not be repeated here.

Chart 1: Ratio of UK General Government Expenditure to UK GDP at Factor Cost 1870 to 2019 (Annual Plots %)

Chart 2 shows the equivalent calculation for the non-oil tax burden expressed as a share of non-oil GDP also measured at factor cost. Oil revenues are trivial nowadays but were significant in the 1980s, for example, and tend to distort the historic record. Table 1 has already shown the differences that arise when alternative GDP measures are employed to measure the tax burden and several such measures are maintained on the author’s data bank  (charts of total taxes/total GDP and using other GDP measures are available on request).

Chart 2: Ratio of UK Non-Oil Taxes to UK Non-Oil GDP at Factor Cost 1900 to 2019 (Annual Plots %)

One thing that should be apparent from Chart 2 is that it is difficult to get the non-oil tax burden to stay above 39% of factor cost GDP for any length of time (horizontal line above). This is despite massive changes to the structure of taxation and the various key rates of tax over this period. Even during World War II, when the UK economy was largely Sovietised to maximise military production, the tax burden only averaged 37.5%, with a temporary peak of 43.5% in 1945. The only other breach of the 39% ceiling occurred in 1969, following the first International Monetary Fund (IMF) bail out of the UK economy.

Now, there are powerful Laffer curve and supply-side arguments to explain why some such barrier exists; particularly, in a small open economy, such as Britain’s, whose ability to compete is likely to be undermined by a relatively high tax burden. Supply-side theory states that the supply of tradable goods and services shifts from high-tax to low-tax economies over time, hollowing out the productive base of the former.

However, one straightforward reason, in terms of the two truisms above, is that a GDP-defined tax burden of 39% actually represents a burden of almost 71% on the residual private sector (charts 3, 4 and 7) if the state is spending, say, 45% of GDP. Such a burden on effort and enterprise will lead to a withdrawal in the supply of both unless private sector agents are either pure altruists or complete mugs.

Chart 3: Ratio of UK Private Sector Activity to UK GDP at Factor Cost 1870 to 2019 (Annual Plots %)

It is also noteworthy that the severe tax squeeze imposed by Roy Jenkins in 1969 – which represented the post-dated bill for the first Wilson administration’s reckless spending from 1964 onwards – reduced the sustainable growth rate of the UK economy from the 3% to 3½% range previously considered normal to some 1½% in the 1970s. This supply withdrawal contributed significantly to the economic and political crises of the pre-Thatcher era. Some of Jenkins former colleagues also believed that his unpopular tax hikes cost Labour the 1970 election. 

The concern now is that the recent UK growth trend of around 1½% each year will collapse to zero, or remain negative, even after the Covid-19 crisis has burned itself out. This would have horrendous implications for social and political stability, as well as the wider economy. It is also worth noting how massive the likely public sector deficit in 2020-21 is in terms of the yields from increasing the main rates of tax, as calculated by Her Majesty’s Revenue and Customs (HMRC – see: Table 2).

Table 2: Direct Effects of Some Illustrative Tax Changes (£’s million)

 

2021-22

2022-23

2023-24

Change basic rate income tax by 1p

4,700

5,850

5,800

Change all main income tax allowances, starting and basic rate limits by1%

1,050

1,400

1,350

Increase Corporation Tax by 1p

2,400

3,100

3,400

Change class 1 employee main rate by 1p

4,500

4,600

4700

Change class 1 employer rate by 1p

6,600

6,800

7,000

Change standard rate VAT by 1p

6,850

7.050

7,300

Source: HM Revenue & Customs, Direct Effects of Illustrative Tax Changes, 1st May 2020.

However, the HMRC calculations are purely static ones that do not allow for the adverse second round effects that rapidly come to outweigh the initial ones when simulated on properly specified macroeconomic forecasting models. At this point it is worth quoting from the conclusion reached by the Warwick Macroeconomic Modelling Bureau, who ran simulations on all the leading forecasting models of the time (Church et. al (1993) page 87)).

“In order to analyse the impact of the various fiscal policy instruments it is essential to consider both direct and indirect effects. For example, the direct effects of tax changes on government finances can be quantified through an assessment of the size of the tax base to which the tax change is to be applied, and such calculations may measure the short-run impact on government spending quite well. However, over a period beyond the first few months following the tax change, the indirect effects through the operation of the economy as a whole come to dominate. Simulations of models of the macro-economy are the only method of quantifying the size and time profile of these effects.”

This quotation essentially makes the case for employing dynamic rather than static scoring when calculating the fiscal gains from tax increases. To ignore the second-round effects operating at the level of the whole economy is equivalent to assuming that the government is in the same position as a monopolist facing a totally inelastic vertical demand curve. This is only taught as an extreme textbook special case in basic microeconomics, which implies setting your price/tax rate to infinity. It is never considered to be a realistic possibility.

Weaknesses in the OBR Approach

 

Unfortunately, the Office for Budget Responsibility (OBR) macroeconomic model of the economy (and the HM Treasury one before that) sets the medium-term growth of the economy by external assumption, not endogenously. This means that a 100% rate of income tax, for example, has the same output consequences as a 10% rate, unless the OBR forecasters intervene to impose judgement on the forecasts. The technical inability to properly simulate the effects of tax changes in a model where growth (and inflation) are both determined exogenously explains why the OBR may be institutionally too optimistic about the revenue returns from raising rates of tax. I would make a similar caveat about some of the Institute for Fiscal Studies (IFS) tax proposals which also cannot fully allow for second and further round effects for similar reasons.

 

The OBR suggested on page 121 of its 14th July Fiscal Stability Report that a fiscal adjustment of some £64bn might be required to stabilise the public finances in the long run. Table 3 illustrates the consequences for the three largest taxes of trying to raise an extra £60bn in tax overall. The working assumption is that the intention ex ante is to raise £20bn from each individual tax. The table then presents the rate hikes required if there was significant slippage in the tax base and/or adverse feedbacks on the expenditure side caused by the second round, whole economy, effects. The HMRC ready reckoner numbers for 2023-24

(table 2) have been utilised because they show the largest take from a 1p tax hike. The rate hikes required with smaller taxes would be even more marked.

 

The $64,000 question is how big are the adverse feedbacks that arise from increasing individual rates of tax? The simulations carried out on my own forecasting model suggest that only around one third to one half of any ex ante tax hike is achieved ex post, although   these are extremely rough and ready magnitudes which vary depending on the precise simulation being carried out. Allowing, for these quasi-Laffer feedbacks suggests that there would need to be unfeasible rises in individual rates of tax to clear even a significant fraction of the present fiscal deficit. Furthermore, private activity might collapse if such an attempt were to be made because of possible non-linearities in the feedbacks involved.

Table 3: Illustration of the Tax Increases Required to Cut Public Borrowing by £20bn in Each Case from Raising Each of the Three Main Rates of Tax, Depending on Assumed Slippage of Tax Base and Other Adverse Feedbacks

Assumed Slippage of…

Zero

25%

50%

66.7%

Basic Rate Income Tax

3.5p

4.6p

6.9p

10.4p

Class 1 Employer NIC’s

2.9p

3.8p

5.7p

8.6p

Value Added Tax

2.7p

3.7p

5.5p

8.2p

Source: HM Revenue & Customs, Direct Effects of Illustrative Tax Changes, 1st May 2020 and author’s calculations. The table shows the change in the rate of tax required in each case required to cut the PSNB by £20bn. For example, with 50% slippage, the basic rate of income tax would have to go up from 20p in the pound to 26.8p and with two-thirds slippage from 20p to 30.2p to reduce public borrowing by £20bn. This table is intended to be illustrative only. Calculations were performed using more places of decimals than shown here.

Chart 4: Ratio of UK Non-Oil Taxes to Residual Private Sector GDP 1900 to 2019 (Annual Plots %)

In addition, the likelihood of complete adverse Laffer curve effects - i.e., higher rates inducing lower receipts, increased welfare bills, and heightened public borrowing – should theoretically rise exponentially as tax rates go up; this is why it is called a ‘curve’. Putting it simply, a tax increase that reduces public borrowing when public spending is, say, 30% of GDP could exacerbate the deficit if the starting point was 45%. Finally, it is possible to suspect that the HMRC calculations may themselves be over-optimistic about the potential size of the tax base in a post Covid-19 world.

Recent Quarterly Data

Chart 5: Ratio of UK General Government Expenditure to UK GDP at Factor Cost 1956 Q1 to 2020 Q1 (Quarterly Plots %)

It is possible to redraw the earlier charts using quarterly data from 1955 Q1 onwards. This brings out the more recent experience and may be more relevant from a political perspective. However, it has the drawback that the public spending and tax figures are not seasonally adjusted, even though they contain marked seasonal swings. As a result, the charts use four quarter running totals divided by four. The larger scale of Chart 5 shows how far the UK had come off the peak spending ratio recorded in 2010 – which was, arguably, always unsustainable in the long run - but also confirms that the spending ratio had passed its lower point of inflexion and was heading upwards from a historically high base, before the corona virus had  struck.

Chart 6 shows the equivalent quarterly plot to Chart 2. The chart again confirms that it is extremely hard to push the tax burden through the 39% of factor cost GDP barrier which is again shown as a horizontal line on the chart. It also confirms how close the UK economy now is to that historic limit, with a ratio of 37.7% being recorded in the four quarters to 2020 Q1.

Chart 6: Ratio of UK Non-Oil Taxes to UK Non-Oil GDP at Factor Cost 1956 Q1 to 2020 Q1 (Quarterly Plots %)

Conclusion

 

It is hard to avoid the conclusion that the UK was nudging up against the historic upper limits of taxable capacity and sustainable government spending – which one might place at around 34½% and 4%, respectively, of the officially-preferred market price measure of GDP – even before the Covid-19 virus struck. Indeed, one might argue that Mr Johnson’s Bourbon-style, Big Government Conservatism had already been steering the ship of state into the iceberg menaced waters of a fiscal stabilisation crisis in the March 2020 Budget. If the Covid-19 iceberg had not hit the vessel, then it was probable that another of Harold MacMillan’s ‘events’ would have done so during the current Parliament.

Chart 7: Ratio of UK Non-Oil Taxes to Residual Private Sector GDP 1956 Q1 to 2020 Q1 (Quarterly Plots % - Horizontal Line Shows Mean (60.3%))

Against this background, it is hard to be positive. Possibly, the best one can do is emphasise that any attempt by the government to tax its way out would massively backfire economically, worsen the public finances not improve them (see: Alesina et al. (2019)) and leave the Conservatives vulnerable to an anti-tax revolt sweeping through the electorate. De-regulation and tax simplification are both receipt friendly in the long term and have almost no upfront revenue costs. Unfortunately, the gains may be only second order ones compared to the returns from supply-side friendly tax cuts and reforms of high marginal rates. However, enhanced fiscal parsimony will be required if the UK is not to become a permanently stagnant, and low- or negative-growth economy and the international financial markets are to carry on underwriting the UK’s twin fiscal and payments deficits throughout the current Parliament. Otherwise, it may be back to the mid-1970s and the sterling and funding crises that triggered the December 1976 IMF loan (Roberts (2016)).

 

 

References

 

Alesina A, Favero C and Giavazzi F (2019) Austerity: When it Works and When it Does’nt, Princeton University Press, Princeton and Oxford.

Booth PM (2016) Taxation, Government Spending & Economic Growth, Institute of Economic Affairs, London.

Church KB, Mitchell PR, Smith PN and Wallis KF (1993) Comparative Properties of Models of the UK Economy, National Institute Economic Review, August.

Office for Budget Responsibility (2020) Fiscal Sustainability Report, 14th July 2020.

Roberts R (2016) When Britain Went Bust: The 1976 IMF Crisis, OMFIF Press.

Smith DB (2006) Living with Leviathan: Public Spending, Taxes and Economic Performance, Hobart Paper 158, Institute of Economic Affairs, London.

Tanzi V and Schuknecht L (2000) Public Spending in the 20th Century: A Global Perspective, Cambridge University Press.

Tanzi V (2011) Government versus Markets: The Changing Economic Role of the State, Cambridge University Press.

David B Smith

 

David B. Smith studied economics at Trinity College, Cambridge, and the University of Essex before working as a macroeconomic modeller and economic forecaster, predominantly in banks (including the Bank of England) and security houses from 1968 to 2006. He was a Visiting Professor at the University of Derby from 2006 to 2014, Chairman of the Institute of Economic Affairs’ Shadow Monetary Policy Committee between 2003 and 2014, and the Chief Economist working on the Tax Payers Alliance 2020 Tax Commission report published in 2012. David has published numerous papers on fiscal policy, monetary policy and financial regulation since the mid-1970s, in addition to his work as a macroeconomic forecaster.

 

July 2020

14