Written evidence submitted by Professor Richard Murphy (Director at Tax Research LLP)
To properly understand this issue the role of tax in the economy has to be understood.
In this context it is important to note that tax does not fund government spending, as such. That is because, as is now apparent, the government can always spend what it wishes by simply asking the Bank of England to extend the necessary credit for it to meet the cost. The Bank of England can do so by either:
At least £300 billion of funding will be supplied by the Bank of England to the UK government during the course of the financial year 2020/21 using quantitative easing, which type of funding has never yet been reversed[3]. This sum might amount to more than 80% of the deficit this year. Given that deficits of in excess of £100 billion a year are now forecast for the next three years[4], and these forecasts may be optimistic, it is suggested that it is highly likely that this process will be repeated in each of those years as well. The direct relationship between government spending and tax is broken in that case.
Clearly there are limits to the extent to which this process of money creation is desirable if inflation targets are to be met, albeit that it is proving very hard to create inflation of 2% per annum at present, suggesting that insufficient money is being created in this way. Some economists[5] suggests that inflation as a result of this process can only arise when full employment has been reached and there is, as a result, general pressure on wage rates. If this is the case, as seems likely[6], this tangible limit is, unfortunately, a long way from likelihood at present but as and when it is reached additional money can be withdrawn from the economy to balance this central bank money creation by:
Seen in this way, (which accurately describes how government funding actually works at present) tax is just one of the mechanisms used for balancing the government funding equation and is not the source from which spending is made[7].
In this context, and correctly stripped of its direct role in funding spending, tax has six different roles to p[lay within the economy, which are:
1) To ratify the value of the currency: this means that by demanding payment of tax in the currency it has to be used for transactions in the UK;
2) To reclaim the money the government has spent into the economy in fulfilment of its democratic mandate;
3) To redistribute income and wealth;
4) To reprice goods and services;
5) To raise democratic representation - people who pay tax vote;
6) To reorganise the economy i.e. fiscal policy.
It is within this framework for tax that the following comments are provided in answer to your question[8]. The answer requires consideration of three issues:
Each is addressed in turn.
The greatest misunderstanding around tax at present, arising as a direct consequence of the coronavirus crisis, is that there will at some time be an obligation on government to somehow raise tax to cover the deficit of £300 billion or that will arise in 2020/21 and the £100 billion plus deficits that will arise in each of the following three years, as currently forecast. This is not true. There are a number of reasons for this:
It follows that the rational objective for the tax take within fiscal policy is, in this environment, to keep that yield as low as possible in order to stimulate demand, and so encourage economic recovery, leaving QE, the Bank of England and the government savings markets to fulfil the task of balancing the government’s funding equation.
This removal of pressure on the tax system to raise revenue at this time does, however, give rise to a considerable benefit when it comes to addressing the necessary tax reforms required to equip the UK with the tax system it needs that might be suitable for the twenty first century. Proposals to achieve these objectives are noted in the answers to questions 3, 5, 6, 7, 8, 10 and 11 of this submission and so are not repeated here.
There is a tax reform not mentioned elsewhere in this submission that would assist the government in addressing environmental and demographic issues now.
It is widely recognised that a Green New Deal is now an essential reform programme if the problems of climate change are to be addressed. In work I have undertaken with Colin Hines, the convenor of the UK Green New Deal Group, of which I am member, we have suggested[9] that the cost of this programme may be £100 billion a year, or at least five per cent of UK GDP. The point already made about the need to avoid tax increases being noted, we have proposed that this programme be paid for with borrowing and newly created funds. Whilst there is already a vibrant market for government bonds, to encourage the sale of the bonds to be used for this purpose we have proposed some simple rule changes to ISAs and pension contributions that could ensure that all the funds required for the Green New Deal could come from these two sources, if need be.
Firstly, we have noted that collectively £70 billion a year is saved in different kinds of ISA accounts[10]. If, to secure this tax free status these funds had to be invested in Green New Deal bonds paying an average of around 1.1 per cent, which is the current offering on National Savings and Investment accounts, then we have no doubt that all this sum would be available for investment in the Green New Deal each year.
In addition, if pension rules were changed so that in exchange for the tax relief given on these contributions, which reliefs cost £54 billion a year at present[11], 25 per cent of all contributions had to be invested in Green New Deal related bonds then more than £25 billion could come into the Green New Deal programme from this source as well.
In other words, two straightforward changes in savings rules could provide all the funds required to purchase the Green New Deal bonds that will be issued to finance this programme. It really is that simple.
The point is made to make clear that the alignment of tax reliefs, rates and allowances with broader economic and social policy is possible. And since the Green New Deal is both designed to create jobs in every constituency and to help bridge the demographic divide by using the savings of older people in the population to provide jobs for younger generations those issues are also addressed by this proposal.
The first reform that the UK could adopt to address the issues noted is to require that all multinational corporations trading in the UK publish their annual accounts for filing with Companies House on a country-by-country reporting basis, whether or not they have their head office in this country. The right to demand such accounts on public record in the UK so that the UK public have the right to know whether or not the tax paid by the multinational corporations that they trade with make fair and appropriate payment of tax in the UK as a result of the activity that they undertake here will be entirely within the power of the UK to demand post-Brexit.
The current best example of the potential country-by-country reporting disclosures that might be required of multinational corporations in this way is provided by the 2019 standard on this issue published by GRI (the Global Reporting Initiative)[12] [13]. There can be no doubt that public pressure will provide the best mechanism to create demand for companies to reform their taxation practices, and country-by-country reporting data published on a consistent and reliable basis will provide the public with the information that they need as consumers to bring that pressure to bear.
There would be no significant additional cost on companies to comply with this requirement since the standard is based on, and is a development from, the information that almost all multinational corporations in all major economies must now supply to their tax authorities on a country-by-country reporting basis for tax risk appraisal purposes. As such all multinational corporations should already have the information to deliver this information in their possession already.
The second basis on which reform could be made would be for the UK to adopt a unitary apportionment formula basis for the taxation of multinational corporations. This would remove from debate all the disputes that arise as a result of the existing international tax system which assumes that:
A unitary apportionment basis for the taxation of a multinational corporation assumes it is a single entity and is managed as such. Its single profit is then apportioned to the countries where it trades based on a formula. The most common formula weights profit before tax (P) on the basis of where third party sales (S), employees (E) and tangible assets (A) are located on the basis of the following formula to determine the profit attributable to a location (L) as opposed to the corporation as a whole (C):
PL = PC x (SL/SC +EL/EC+AL/AC)/3
Other options are available, for example to allow for environmental extraction, but this is the usual default option that is discussed.
It is, of course, possible to claim that the result is arbitrary, but so too is the existing system.
In addition, it can be claimed that a formula could not be agreed, but nor is it required that transfer prices be agreed between countries now.
What is apparent is that this basis of tax provides a viable and continuing system for corporate taxation on an international basis when the existing system is unsustainable because it is based on assumptions that have no relationship to the real world, whereas those underpinning unitary taxation reflect the economic reality of there being a single entity under common control, which is what a multinational corporation is. It is for this reason that the UK should adopt this basis of tax, even if it would be a pioneer in this field. Doing so would provide multinational corporations based in this country with the certainty that they need on the taxation liabilities that they might owe in this country.
If the UK is to provide business with some certainty then it needs to transform its corporation tax system. This would demonstrate that it is a pioneer that is willing to provide multinational corporations with the basis of certainty that they need to plan and develop whilst they concentrate on more important issues of future concern to them, like their adaptation to climate change.
The last two decades, during which tax planning has been seen as a basis for corporate profit generation, are now being seen as part of a model of business activity that belongs to another era (the BC, or ‘before Covid’ era). In the AC (‘after Covid’) era business has other priorities, which will include both basic survival and the demands for meeting zero-carbon targets that will shift corporate management focus from tax onto other issues.
Businesses representatives frequently say that what they want with regard to tax is certainty: the noted reforms could provide this and provide competitive advantage to the UK and its businesses as a result. These reforms, and the other tax reforms noted in this submission, are an essential part of that new approach to tax in the AC era.
Total UK tax in come as a percentage of GDP has varied relatively little over the last twenty years:
Source: Author calculations based upon HM treasury and Office for Budget Responsibility budget reports over the period
This revenue is low for a country like the UK by international standards. Data from the OECD for 2000 – 2018 provides the following data for all member states (the black line, which is very close to the UK throughout the whole period ,is the OECD average) with France and Germany being highlighted for the sake of comparison:
Source: Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development[14]
As is apparent from this data, France and Germany do not appear to suffer for having higher overall tax rates than the UK. There is, in fact, strong evidence that the higher the aggregate total tax paid in a country the higher is its GDP per capita. The following data relates to the year 2013 and shows this relationship for 175 countries and was included in my book ‘The Joy of Tax’ (Random House, 2015):
As the trend line makes clear, the relationship is strongly positive. There is, as a result, no clear evidence that there is an obvious overall limit to the level of taxation that the UK economy can bear without undesirable or counterproductive harm to economic growth.
What, however, is also clear, is that the ability to pay additional tax varies considerably across the economy. Research undertaken in April 2020 by the author of this submission[15] showed that in the period from 2011 to 2018 the total national income of the UK was £13.1 trillion. In that same period the increase in net wealth was £5.1 trillion. It is stressed that this latter figure is not for total wealth, but the increase in the value of that net wealth in that period.
That research then showed that the overall effective tax rates on income during this period were unlikely to have averaged more than 29.4%, but those on wealth increases did not exceed 3.4%.
It then noted that if these rates had been equalised it would, at least in principle, have been possible to raise an additional £174 billion in tax revenue per annum from the owners of wealth.
Finally it was noted that because there had been no attempt at equalisation of tax rates on income derived from work and wealth and because the distribution of the ownership of wealth varies substantially across the UK, including by age and gender, the effective tax rate of the 10% of those in the UK who are in the lowest earning group of income taxpayers exceeds 42% of their combined income and wealth gains in a year, but the equivalent effective tax rate for those in the highest ten percent of UK income taxpayers ranked by earnings is less than half that at just over 18 percent.
Graphically this is represented as follows:
Sources: Author’s calculations based on Office for National Statistics, HM Revenue & Customs and HM Treasury data
It is, as a result, suggested that there is considerable additional capacity for tax to be raised from those who own most of the wealth in the UK, many of whom are in that top ten per cent of income earners.
At the same time, it is also noted that those with the lowest levels of income in the UK have the least capacity to pay any additional taxes, and that there might be considerable advantage from reducing the tax rates that they pay. This is not just for social reasons resulting from the reduction of the impact of inequality in the UK: the benefit would also be to the economy as a whole because those with the lowest levels of income have the highest marginal propensity to consume in society and when there is a shortage of demand in the economy (as is likely to the case for a number of years) providing those with that highest propensity to consume with additional income is one of the most effective measures for stimulating economic activity that can be taken.
As noted in the answer to question 8 of this submission, much of the tax advantage to those with wealth comes from:
The resulting necessary reforms to the tax system are discussed in the answers to questions 2, 3, 5, 6, 7, 8, 10 and 11 of this submission.
As noted in the answers to questions 2 and 3, there is an urgent need for reform of corporation tax in the UK.
As noted in the answer provided to questions 8, there is also an urgent need to reform the exemptions, allowances and reliefs provided within many of the UK’s taxes that have between them a current annual cost of at least £425 billion of tax foregone, little of which is explained or justified by HMRC or HM Treasury, and few of which are appraised for their economic, social or fiscal effectiveness.
As noted in the answer to question 10, the UK tax system needs radical reform if it is to become truly progressive and appropriately and fairly tax income from varying sources as if they were of equal worth in the hands of the recipient (which as a matter of fact they are) when the current tax system heavily penalises income generated from work.
As noted in questions 1 and 11, the reasons for charging tax, and so designing appropriate tax systems, have to also now be properly understood within the framework of a twenty first economy where the government has its own currency and central bank, meaning it is no longer reliant on either tax or financial markets to fund its expenditure. As noted in the answer to question 11, this requires substantial rethinking of the management approach to, and actual management of, taxation, and that demands reform within HMRC itself.
There are, in addition, two other aspects of tax reform not mentioned elsewhere which need to be noted here. These are the need for the reform of company law regulation within the UK and the need for enhanced automatic information exchange within the UK economy to prevent tax abuse. Each is dealt with in turn.
There is a dispute as to the true scale of the UK tax gap. HMRC has suggested it to be around £30 billion per annum for more than a decade[16]. My research suggests it to be considerably higher[17]. My research suggests that much of the UK tax gap might occur within the UK’s missing companies[18].
The number of companies in the UK has risen significantly during the present century:
Source: Companies House data
Over the years 2007-08 to 2017-18 (the most recent for which data is available[19]) HMRC data suggests that on average only 40% of companies had trading income whilst over the period 2007-08 to 2011-12 just 58% of companies were asked to submit tax returns by HMRC[20]. If this trend has continued, and the data is remarkably consistent over time, it is likely that HKRC now has no knowledge at all of the activities of approximately 1.8 million companies in the UK and that another near 800,000 report themselves to have no income although it would seem that HMRC undertake almost no checking to prove that this is the case. Why this is the case is hard to explain.
My research, based on Companies House data[21], suggests that 93% of companies dissolved and removed from the Companies House register are ‘struck off’ each year i.e. no formal oversight of the process of removal takes place and reliance is instead placed on a statement from the directors that the company has not traded prior to dissolution, excepting in those 47% of such cases where the Registrar of Companies had to initiate the striking off because the company had failed to comply with its legal obligation to file accounts or a Confirmation Statement (formerly, the Annual Return).
Over the last five years Companies House data shows that an average of 472,000 companies have been removed from the register of companies each year. The above noted data suggests that nothing might be known about the last trading of more than 200,000 of these each year, and this assumes that all other companies have, of course, been honest in the declarations that they have made.
This is a system that appears to be designed, if only by omission, to facilitate tax evasion, and it seems that HMRC pays no attention to it, concentrating its efforts on the tax returns it gets and not those it does not receive. This provides significant opportunity for abuse in the UK economy that means that the shadow economy is very likely to be much larger than that HMRC records, as VAT tax gap data would also imply. This issue now needs to be addressed within the UK economy.
It is stressed that the consequence is not just tax lost: this failing to regulate companies undermines the level playing field that is necessary for fair competition within the UK because it permits abuse that undermines honest companies. A pro-business policy from any government would seek to tackle this abuse for reasons of upholding fair competition as well as for the reason of maintaining tax revenue. It is very hard to understand why such laxness in regulation is permitted by both HMRC and Companies House.
This issue could be addressed by automatic information exchange, as noted in the next section.
Automatic information exchange of data on potentially taxable income from banks and other agencies to HMRC has a very long history in the UK. For example, banks have reported interest paid to UK taxpayers to HMRC for very many decades, whilst PAYE ensures that employers provide information on the payments that they make to their employees on a regular basis. The principle is as a consequence well established, understood and, most importantly, is widely accepted.
The idea of automatic information exchange has been more widely adopted in recent years, in particular with regard to attempts to tackle tax haven abuse. As a result it is now accepted that international automatic information exchange is normal. So, for example, it is now the case that a UK tax resident customer of a bank in the Cayman Island will not only have information supplied to HMRC with regard to their personal bank accounts, but the Cayman bank in question will also be responsible for supplying information to HMRC on their other financial interests and data on the activity of those interests e.g. information will be supplied on the companies that they own and the trusts of which they are a beneficiary. As a result it is possible to trace whether they might have income arising from those sources.
Although this is now the case with regard to tax havens and other countries the same is not true within the UK itself. So, for example, whilst there has been some recent improvements in transparency from payment platforms (credit card suppliers, PayPal, etc) to HMRC it remains the case that a bank or other regulated financial services sector supplier does not need to supply annual information to HMRC on all those companies to whom they supply services or account facilities in the UK, including data on:
If this information had to be supplied by banks and other regulated financial services entities annually for all their clients then the likelihood that corporate tax abuse of the type noted previously in this answer could be curtailed would increase significantly.
If banks also had to report all those persons with irregular deposit patterns within their bank accounts over a minimum sum then it is also likely that those moonlighting in self employment might be identified.
In addition, if all financial services advisers who assisted on capital transactions had to supply HMRC with data of transactions they had assisted with in a year (in essence, in many cases, by supplying copies of client account statements) non-reporting of a great many capital transactions would cease.
And, if rental agents had to supply copies of their landlord client accounts then abuse in that sector would also be reduced.
Research in the USA[22] has shown that when a taxpayer is aware that a source of income is being declared to their tax authority the rate of tax compliance increases considerably. The whole purpose of this recommendation is to encourage that compliance on the part of taxpayers within the UK tax system when this is too low at present.
It is suggested that these issues are the priority for reform within the UK tax system, and will require considerable and sustained effort over a number of years to deliver.
These issues are addressed in the answers to questions 2, 5, 7, 8, 10 and 11, in particular and are not repeated here.
The current system of tax reliefs in the UK is disorganised. It lacks policy focus. Few of the reliefs provided are subject to any regular appraisal as to their economic justification. They frequently undermine the integrity of the tax system as a whole (see the answer to question 8 for amplification in this issue). Based on recent research these allowances and reliefs might in total cost £425 billion a year, spread across taxes as shown in the table in the answer to question 8. Collectively they do as a consequence represent the single biggest expenditure element in the whole of the government’s budget. Despite that they attract almost no scrutiny at all. This is a situation that requires reform.
It is not the suggestion of this submission that all current tax reliefs, exemptions and allowances are inappropriate. There are some reliefs that would, almost inevitably, survive in any tax system, such as the individual personal allowance for income tax purposes, although no judgement is implied in saying so on its current level, availability and the restrictions that apply to it. Nor is comment offered on current tax rates, or the rates at which tax relief is made available (although this issue is addressed to some degree in the answer to question 10). Instead the intention is to note the policy issues inherent within the current framework of allowances and reliefs, of which there are many that need addressing. The issues that arise relate in particular to:
Each of these issues will be addressed in turn.
As noted in the answer to Question 1, if tax is to be properly understood within a modern fiat currency economy, its primary function is to collect revenue to negate the inflationary risk arising from government spending and its secondary function is to impact the delivery of government social, economic and fiscal policy.
In the context of tax’s primary role of controlling inflation, the preponderance of allowances, reliefs and exemptions available within the UK tax system does not help the control of fiscal policy within the economy. This is because their take up is unpredictable, and even the measurement of their use is in some cases hard to appraise because allowances, reliefs and exemptions can effectively eliminate the requirement to report the information needed to undertake that appraisal. If tax is to fulfil its primary goal as a tool of fiscal policy it is desirable that the number of tax reliefs, allowances and exemptions be kept to the minimum possible to achieve the goals of taxation as a whole, taking into consideration the impact of tax on the government’s social and economic agendas. There is no indication that this is the case at present.
It should also be noted that the logic underpinning many allowances, exemptions and reliefs is now known to be economically inappropriate. For example, many allowances (including pension tax reliefs, ISA tax reliefs, additional income tax allowances for savings income and many investment related reliefs in income tax and capital gains tax) are based on the logic that saving is a necessary pre-condition of investment within the UK economy. This is now known not to be the case. Almost all investment is now funded by bank credit, which the Bank of England has acknowledged since 2014 to be created without reference to the availability of bank deposits[23]. In addition, very little of the sum that is described as being invested in the stock market is actually used to fund new share issues by companies registered on that exchange, meaning that almost none of the significant amount of savings direct towards equity investment does actually result in new economic activity. The funds saved in that way do, instead, mainly fuel increases in share prices. It is very questionable therefore whether those tax incentives designed to encourage saving are economically well directed at present.
A large number of the allowances and reliefs provided within the tax system are targeted at those who have the means to save. This does, for example apply to the reliefs for pension contributions paid, ISA reliefs, tax exemptions for financial services within VAT, reinvestment and other allowances within capital gains tax, and others. The combined cost of these allowances is considerable. Such reliefs and allowances have the effect of increasing the financial net worth of those already able to afford to save and as such have the net consequence of increasing financial inequality within the UK, which has significant social consequences and economic cost. When many of these reliefs are also poorly targeted with regard to their economic consequences in that they do not actually promote investment, as noted previously, their desirability, given the cost involved, has to be questioned.
Since this point is noted in answer to Question 8 it is not repeated here, but the risk that poorly designed tax reliefs, allowances and exemptions can create tax spillover effects that undermine the integrity of the tax system as a whole is high, and is the result of the poor design of many of them that requires rectification.
To understand this issue the difference between the entirely legitimate tax advice industry and the activity of abusive tax planning has to be understood. This has been best explained by UK based tax barrister David (now Clair) Quentin[24].
As they have explained, if there is no risk of a transaction being challenged by a tax authority - because it is completely compliant with the letter and spirit of UK tax law - then even if it reduces the amount of tax to be paid by a taxpayer it cannot be considered to be tax avoidance. This is explained in this diagram from Quentin:
A person who is uncertain of the law is represented by the red circle on the vertical axis. If they take advice from their tax authority or a professional tax adviser they might as a consequence considerably reduce their tax risk by increasing the certainty that their affairs are legally compliant: this explains the red line up the Y, vertical, axis. Tax advice reduces legal uncertainty, in the first instance. This is a socially useful activity.
Thereafter they might also make other choices permitted, and even encouraged, by law that reduce the amount of tax that they might pay e.g. they might make payment into a pension or claim permissible tax reliefs for expenses that they have actually incurred. Both are permitted if relevant rules are complied with, even if less tax is paid as a result. This explains the horizontal red line across the top of the chart. Advice that has these reliefs and allowances are available to a taxpayer is entirely legitimate, and is, once more, a useful activity for tax advisers to undertake. It is reasonable to presume that a claim for a tax relief when claimed within the spirit of the law is a socially appropriate action.
However, a point is then reached where further reduction in tax paid is not possible without uncertain tax positions being adopted. An uncertain tax position is one where, for example, a transaction is represented as being something that it might not be, or is one which is at least open to either legal or factual challenge. The point when such positions are adopted is that where the line begins to slope downwards. Thereafter, uses are made of the law which are clearly open to doubt as to their legal validity: many marketed tax avoidance schemes are of this type. The activity undertaken is no longer within the spirit of the law. Instead, that law is abused.
The inflection point where tax expenditure becomes tax avoidance is clearly marked by the pointing finger on the diagram. As a person descends down the slope on the right-hand side of the diagram the uncertainty in the position that they have adopted increases until what is described as aggressive tax avoidance is being undertaken.
The provision of numerous, unmonitored, and often ambiguous tax exemptions, reliefs and allowances encourage this process of submitting uncertain tax positions within tax returns supplied to HMRC. This happens for a number of reasons. Firstly, the simple existence of the opportunity to reduce tax is an incentive to sum to abuse. Secondly, whenever there is legislation there is room for interpretation, which can create the opportunity for abuse. Thirdly, such are the differentials in the tax rates available as a consequence of some of these allowances and reliefs that the temptation to represent a transaction as falling within the scope of them is so great that some will fabricate evidence to support such a claim. Fourthly, there is widespread awareness that the number of tax investigations into claims made is now very low in numerical terms , and this encourages abuse. Fifth, because there are some within the tax abuse profession who are willing to provide legal cover for these activities the risks to some taxpayers (and, in particular, corporate taxpayers) from partaking in these activities is very low. Sixthly, since if appropriate tax advice has been taken in advance the risk of tax penalties resulting from the submission of such false positions is limited, the risk advantage from abusing tax reliefs, exemptions and allowances lies very largely with the taxpayer.
It is not suggested that all aggressive tax planning would be eliminated if tax reliefs, allowances and exemptions were eliminated, but since almost all tax planning takes place at the boundaries between different parts of the tax system a reduction in their number would undoubtedly reduce the opportunity for abuse. It should be noted that greater activity on the part of HMRC would also help, as is noted in the answer to question 11.
In 2018/19 tax year there were tax reliefs of £425 billion in total granted in the UK over a range of taxes, as noted below. This figure does include items like the income tax personal allowance, basic exemptions from national insurance contributions and VAT allowances, but the point to be made is that all these allowances massively reduce the potential tax yield from every UK tax, as the following table shows:
Tax revenues for 2018 – 19 tax year taking the cost of tax reliefs and allowances into account
Tax | Gross notional tax revenues when the cost of tax reliefs and allowances is taken into account | Cost of tax reliefs and allowances | Net tax receipts reported by the Office for Budget Responsibility |
| £’bn | £’bn | £’bn |
Income tax | 336 | 151 | 185 |
National insurance contributions | 221 | 87 | 134 |
Excise duties | 49 | 0 | 49 |
Corporation tax | 84 | 29 | 55 |
VAT | 244 | 99 | 145 |
Business rates | 30 | 0 | 30 |
Council tax | 34 | 0 | 34 |
Other taxes | 145 | 59 | 86 |
Other non-taxes | 51 | 0 | 51 |
Total | 1,194 | 425 | 769 |
Sources: Author calculations based on HM Treasury (2018)[25]and HMRC (2019)[26]
If consideration is to be given to tax simplification then the place to start is by reviewing these tax reliefs, exemptions and allowances. In particular, the interaction between these allowances and reliefs and the objectives of fiscal policy, tackling inequality and repricing market failure all need to be considered.
In this context the adoption of an approach called tax spillover analysis has much to recommend it. It is appropriate to note that this methodology has largely been pioneered Professor Andrew Baker of the University of Sheffield[27] and me. A note on this approach is attached as an appendix to this submission.
Tax spillovers as defined by the International Monetary Fund in 2014, were understood as the effects one country’s tax rules and practices had on others. They were thought to be caused by and confined to reductions in corporation tax, primarily arising between different countries. My research with Andrew Baker showed that spillovers, consisting of tax policies and practices that do harm to, or undermine tax bases and the functioning of tax systems overall (often unintentionally), were a much broader and diverse phenomenon than had been previously thought. The work showed how harmful spillover effects went beyond corporation tax and could arise from the interactions between different areas of tax policy and administration within the same country, and so could be domestic as well as international. The framework that we have created for qualitatively assessing a country's overall tax spillovers, that both diagnoses existing spillovers and identifies potential policy remedies and reforms, is designed as a mechanism to make tax systems less internally inconsistent and to secure tax bases. That is why it would be appropriate for the UK to undertake such an exercise now.
There are a number of reasons for governments and their agencies to assess spillovers in this way. Firstly, they might be seeking to raise additional tax revenue without increasing tax rates, or extending the tax base. Second, they may be seeking to uphold the rule of law. Third, they may be trying to improve fiscal management of the economy. Fourth, they may be seeking to ensure that the incentives and other arrangements to encourage particular behaviours built into the tax system work to best effect. Fifth, they might be seeking to promote economic and social justice by making sure that everyone pays their share of the taxes owing, creating a level-playing field. Sixth, governments may be concerned about the investment they are making in tax authorities and wondering whether those funds are being used to best effect. Finally, they may be concerned about their international tax relations and the way international tax competition might erode their tax base and limit their fiscal autonomy. In short, spillover assessment can present an overall picture of how taxes and their administration interact with other parts of the tax system and with what consequences. We would be pleased to provide further evidence on this issue if you require it.
Based on a sample review of the UK tax system that we have undertaken using our tax spillover methodology[28] we noted the following:
The only reason why a windfall tax might be proposed at present is to repay the national debt.
As was noted by the Chancellor of the Exchequer[29] in a reply to his predecessor in parliament on 8 July 2020:
Sajid Javid (Bromsgrove) (Con)
I commend my right hon. Friend’s statement and the actions he has taken to ensure that we get the strongest possible recovery. He has been absolutely right thus far to spend “whatever it takes”—something he set out clearly back in March—but he will be acutely aware that interest rates will not stay low forever and that we will eventually need to bring our national debt back under control in order to sustain recovery, continue to create jobs and keep taxes low. So may I encourage him to set out new fiscal rules in his autumn Budget with the aim of getting our national debt down as a proportion of our national income by the end of this Parliament.
Rishi Sunak
I thank my right hon. Friend for his kind support and also his advice. He is of course absolutely right, and I hope that he was heartened by what he heard me say in the statement about the importance of returning our public finances to a sustainable footing in the medium term. We can and will do exactly that. He is right to highlight the sensitivity of our debt to interest rates, which was why he was right to introduce into our fiscal framework the notion of an interest service rule, and that is something that I will look at keenly in the coming months.
The logic of this exchange is inherent in the calls for a windfall tax: its only aim would be to reduce the level of the so-called UK national debt, which might be better called UK national savings for the reasons noted in answer to question 1. However, this is unnecessary because there is no need to repay UK national debt, which has steadily increased since 1694. In addition, as latest budget forecasts show[30] the anticipated cost of servicing this debt is also falling over the next few years, even as it notionally increases in value.
In addition, that debt is currently misstated by UK official statistics, including those issued by the Office for National Statistics. That is because, as the UK Whole of Government Accounts show[31], UK government debt should be stated net of quantitative easing. If this is the case the pattern of UK national debt growth is as follows, based on Office for Budget Responsibility data: